Your browser doesn't support javascript.
loading
Show: 20 | 50 | 100
Results 1 - 8 de 8
Filter
1.
Eur J Health Econ ; 24(5): 673-678, 2023 Jul.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-35921019

ABSTRACT

BACKGROUND: Empiric prescription to treat infectious diseases in community care settings has caused antibiotics to be overprescribed, increasing antimicrobial resistance (AMR). To reduce antibiotics prescription, the use of point-of-care diagnostic testing (POCT) has been suggested. METHODS: We present a stylized static theoretical economic model to analyse whether the use of POCT always decreases antibiotics prescriptions. We consider the interaction of a group of doctors who differ in their level of concern about AMR when prescribing with a firm selling a POCT, and we characterize the price set by the manufacturer and doctors' decision to employ POCT. RESULTS: We found that the number of antibiotics prescriptions is not always lower. This result depends on the distribution of the doctors' concern about AMR as there is a proportion of doctors who use POCT and then prescribe antibiotics while other doctors change their prescribing behaviour after using POCT and stop giving antibiotics to patients who do not benefit from them. When the proportion of patients who need antibiotic treatment is higher than the proportion of doctors who use POCT and stop prescribing unnecessary antibiotics, the number of antibiotics prescriptions is larger. Our analysis also shows that the use of POCT improves health outcomes. CONCLUSIONS: We should be very careful when we assert that POCT reduces antibiotics prescriptions as there are situations in which the opposite effect occurs.


Subject(s)
Anti-Bacterial Agents , Communicable Diseases , Humans , Anti-Bacterial Agents/therapeutic use , Point-of-Care Testing , Prescriptions , Diagnostic Techniques and Procedures
2.
Health Econ Rev ; 11(1): 29, 2021 Aug 09.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-34370115

ABSTRACT

BACKGROUND: Antibiotics have been overprescribed to treat infectious diseases and have generated antimicrobial resistances that reduce their effectiveness. Following the rationale behind the new paradigm of personalized medicine, point-of-care diagnostic testing (POCT) has been proposed to improve the quality of antibiotic prescription with the aim of reducing antimicrobial resistances. METHODS: In order to understand whether this recommendation is valid, we create a theoretical economic model to determine under which conditions the expected benefits of using POCT to guide antibiotic prescription are greater than for empiric prescription, where we define the expected benefits as the difference between the economic value of health and the costs of the treatment. We consider the interaction of a group of physicians who express differing levels of uncertainty when prescribing with a firm selling a diagnostic device, and analyse the firm's pricing policy and the physicians' prescribing decisions. We allow the physicians to internalize the external costs of antimicrobial resistances. RESULTS: We find that the use of POCT reduces the number of antibiotic prescriptions. The reduction in antibiotic prescriptions is higher when physicians internalise the costs of antimicrobial resistances. Physicians with relatively high levels of uncertainty use POCT as they are uncertain about the right treatment for a large proportion of patients. Physicians with low levels of uncertainty prefer to prescribe empirically. The segmentation in the population of physicians regarding the uptake of POCT depends on the distribution of levels of uncertainty across physicians. For each test, the firm charges the marginal production costs of the inputs needed to administer the test, and makes its profit from the sales of the testing devices. CONCLUSIONS: From a theoretical perspective, our findings corroborate the fact that POCT improve the quality of antibiotic prescription and reduce the number of prescriptions. Nevertheless, their use is not always recommended as empiric therapy may be preferred when uncertainty is low.

3.
Health Econ Rev ; 9(1): 28, 2019 Oct 29.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-31664604

ABSTRACT

BACKGROUND: Currently, personalised medicine is becoming more frequently used and many drug companies are including this strategy to gain market access for very specialized therapies. In this article, in order to understand the relationships between the health authority and the drug company when deciding upon the implementation of personalized medicines, we take a theoretical perspective to model it when the price and reimbursement policy follows a pay-for-performance scheme. During the development of a new drug, the firm must decide whether to generate additional knowledge by investing in additional resources to stratify the target population based on a biomarker or directly apply for marketing authorization for the new treatment without information on the characteristics of patients who could respond to it. In this context, we assume that the pricing policy is set by the health authority, and then we characterize the pricing and investment decisions contingent on the rate of response to the treatment. RESULTS: We find that the price when the firm carries out R&D leading to the personalized treatments is not necessarily higher than the price if the firm does not carry out the R&D investment. When the rate of response to the treatment is too low, then the new drug is not marketed. If the rate of response is too high, personalized medicine is not implemented. For intermediate values of the rate of response, the adoption of personalized medicine may occur if the investment costs are sufficiently low; otherwise, the treatment is given to all patients without additional information on their characteristics. The higher the quality of the genetic test (in terms of its sensitivity and specificity), the wider the interval for the values of the proportional responders for which personalized medicine may be implemented. CONCLUSIONS: Our findings show that pre-approval incentives (prices) to promote the personalized treatments depend on the specific characteristics of the disease and the efficacy of the treatment. The model gives an intuitive idea about what to expect in terms of price incentives when the possibility of personalizing treatments becomes a strategic decision for the stakeholders.

5.
Int J Health Econ Manag ; 17(4): 413-432, 2017 Dec.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-28508248

ABSTRACT

In this paper we carry out a vertical differentiation duopoly model applied to pharmaceutical markets to analyze how endogenous and exogenous generic reference pricing influence competition between generic and branded drugs producers. Unlike the literature, we characterize for the exogenous case the equilibrium prices for all feasible relevant reference prices. Competition is enhanced after the introduction of a reference pricing system. We also compare both reference pricing systems on welfare grounds, assuming two different objective functions for health authorities: (i) standard social welfare and (ii) gross consumer surplus net of total pharmaceutical expenditures. We show that regardless of the objective function, health authorities will never choose endogenous reference pricing. When health authorities are paternalistic, the exogenous reference price that maximizes standard social welfare is such that the price of the generic drug is the reference price while the price of the branded drug is higher than the reference price. When health authorities are not paternalistic, the optimal exogenous reference price is such that the price of the branded drug is the reference price while the price of the generic drug is lower than the reference price.


Subject(s)
Costs and Cost Analysis/methods , Drug Costs/statistics & numerical data , Drugs, Generic/economics , Economic Competition/statistics & numerical data , Humans , Models, Econometric , Paternalism , Social Welfare , United States
7.
Eur J Health Econ ; 16(9): 985-94, 2015 Dec.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-25381039

ABSTRACT

OBJECTIVE: To contribute to the theoretical literature on personalized medicine, analyzing and integrating in an economic model, the decision a health authority faces when it must decide on the implementation of personalized medicine in a context of uncertainty. METHODS: We carry out a stylized model to analyze the decision health authorities face when they do not have perfect information about the best treatment for a population of patients with a given disease. The health authorities decide whether to use a test to match patients with treatments (personalized medicine) to maximize health outcomes. Our model characterizes the situations under which personalized medicine dominates the alternative option of business-as-usual (treatment without previous test). We apply the model to the KRAS test for colorectal cancer, the PCA3 test for prostate cancer and the PCR test for the X-fragile syndrome, to illustrate how the parameters and variables of the model interact. RESULTS: Implementation of personalized medicine requires, as a necessary condition, having some tests with high discriminatory power. This is not a sufficient condition and expected health outcomes must be taken into account to make a decision. When the specificity and the sensitivity of the test are low, the health authority prefers to apply a treatment to all patients without using the test. When both characteristic of the test are high, the health authorities prefer to personalize the treatments when expected health outcomes are better than those under the standard treatment. When we applied the model to the three aforementioned tests, the results illustrate how decisions are adopted in real world. CONCLUSIONS: Although promising, the use of personalized medicine is still under scrutiny as there are important issues demanding a response. Personalized medicine may have an impact in the drug development processes, and contribute to the efficiency and effectiveness of health care delivery. Nevertheless, more accurate statistical and economic information related to tests results and treatment costs as well as additional medical information on the efficacy of the treatments are needed to adopt decisions that incorporate economic rationality.


Subject(s)
Genetic Testing/methods , Genetic Testing/standards , Models, Econometric , Precision Medicine/economics , Colorectal Neoplasms/economics , Colorectal Neoplasms/genetics , Cost-Benefit Analysis , Fragile X Syndrome/economics , Fragile X Syndrome/genetics , Humans , Male , Prostatic Neoplasms/economics , Prostatic Neoplasms/genetics , Quality-Adjusted Life Years , Sensitivity and Specificity
8.
An Med Interna ; 14(1): 9-14, 1997 Jan.
Article in Spanish | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-9091042

ABSTRACT

This study calculates the costs of the prevalence of chronic heart failure in Spain during 1993. Since the precise values of the rate of prevalence are unknown, two calculation procedures are designs. In order to proxy the rate of prevalence two different questionnaires are addressed to primary care doctors and to cardiologists. The registers of discharged patients from hospitals are also used for obtaining this rate. The so computed prevalence rate turned out to be 5.3 per thousand. Nevertheless a rate of 10 per thousand is also used for the cost calculation. The reason is that this last value is located in the middle of the rank of values quoted by several authors. The annual health service costs are between 64,028 and 110,240 millions pesetas (depending on the assumed prevalence) what means a cost of illness between 1.8 and 3.1% of the Health Department budget for 1993. The study proposes a method to calculate the prevalence of the chronic heart failure that searches simultaneously for information on costing of the clinical treatments, the study also presents disaggregated information by assistance level and their respective economic cost.


Subject(s)
Heart Failure/economics , Cost of Illness , Heart Failure/epidemiology , Humans , Spain/epidemiology
SELECTION OF CITATIONS
SEARCH DETAIL
...