Your browser doesn't support javascript.
loading
Show: 20 | 50 | 100
Results 1 - 20 de 37
Filter
1.
Eur J Health Econ ; 19(5): 757-768, 2018 Jun.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-28762051

ABSTRACT

Most health insurers in the Netherlands apply community-rating and open enrolment for supplementary health insurance, although it is offered at a free market. Theoretically, this should result in adverse selection. There are four indications that adverse selection indeed has started to occur on the Dutch supplementary insurance market. The goal of this paper is to analyze whether premium differentiation would be able to counteract adverse selection. We do this by simulating the uptake and premium development of supplementary insurance over 25 years using data on healthcare expenses and background characteristics from 110,261 insured. For the simulation of adverse selection, it is assumed that only insured for whom supplementary insurance is expected not to be beneficial will consider opting out of the insurance. Therefore, we calculate for each insured the financial profitability (by making assumptions about the consumer's expected claims and the premium set by the insurer), the individual's risk attitude and the probability to opt out or opt in. The simulation results show that adverse selection might result in a substantial decline in insurance uptake. Additionally, the simulations show that if insurers were to differentiate their premium to 28 age and gender groups, adverse selection could be modestly counteracted. Finally, this paper shows that if insurers would apply highly refined risk-rating, adverse selection for this type of supplementary insurance could be counteracted completely.


Subject(s)
Insurance, Health , Risk Adjustment , Insurance Carriers , Netherlands , Risk
2.
Health Econ ; 27(2): e1-e12, 2018 02.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-28544104

ABSTRACT

This study explores the predictive power of interaction terms between the risk adjusters in the Dutch risk equalization (RE) model of 2014. Due to the sophistication of this RE-model and the complexity of the associations in the dataset (N = ~16.7 million), there are theoretically more than a million interaction terms. We used regression tree modelling, which has been applied rarely within the field of RE, to identify interaction terms that statistically significantly explain variation in observed expenses that is not already explained by the risk adjusters in this RE-model. The interaction terms identified were used as additional risk adjusters in the RE-model. We found evidence that interaction terms can improve the prediction of expenses overall and for specific groups in the population. However, the prediction of expenses for some other selective groups may deteriorate. Thus, interactions can reduce financial incentives for risk selection for some groups but may increase them for others. Furthermore, because regression trees are not robust, additional criteria are needed to decide which interaction terms should be used in practice. These criteria could be the right incentive structure for risk selection and efficiency or the opinion of medical experts.


Subject(s)
Health Expenditures , Models, Statistical , Risk Adjustment/methods , Adult , Female , Humans , Insurance, Health/economics , Male , Netherlands
3.
Eur J Health Econ ; 18(2): 209-226, 2017 Mar.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-26857921

ABSTRACT

Adverse selection regarding a voluntary deductible (VD) in health insurance implies that insured only opt for a VD if they expect no (or few) healthcare expenses. This paper investigates two potential strategies to reduce adverse selection: (1) differentiating the premium to the duration of the contract for which the VD holds (ex-ante approach) and (2) differentiating the premium to the number of years for which insured have opted for a VD (ex-post approach). It can be hypothesized that premiums will decrease with the duration of the contract or the number of years for which insured have opted for a VD, providing an incentive to insured to opt for a deductible also in (incidental) years they expect relatively high expenses. To test this hypothesis, we examine which premium patterns would occur under these strategies using data on healthcare expenses and risk characteristics of over 750,000 insured from 6 years. Our results show that, under the assumptions made, only without risk equalization the premiums could decrease with the duration of the contract or the number of years for which insured have opted for a VD. With (sophisticated) risk equalization, decreasing premiums seem unfeasible, both under the ex-ante and ex-post approach. Given these findings, we are sceptical about the feasibility of these strategies to counteract adverse selection.


Subject(s)
Deductibles and Coinsurance/economics , Insurance Carriers/economics , Insurance Selection Bias , Insurance, Health/economics , Humans , Models, Econometric , Risk , Time Factors
5.
Eur J Health Econ ; 17(7): 885-95, 2016 Sep.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-26420555

ABSTRACT

Most competitive social health insurance markets include risk equalization to compensate insurers for predictable variation in healthcare expenses. Empirical literature shows that even the most sophisticated risk equalization models-with advanced morbidity adjusters-substantially undercompensate insurers for selected groups of high-risk individuals. In the presence of premium regulation, these undercompensations confront consumers and insurers with incentives for risk selection. An important reason for the undercompensations is that not all information with predictive value regarding healthcare expenses is appropriate for use as a morbidity adjuster. To reduce incentives for selection regarding specific groups we propose overpaying morbidity adjusters that are already included in the risk equalization model. This paper illustrates the idea of overpaying by merging data on morbidity adjusters and healthcare expenses with health survey information, and derives three preconditions for meaningful application. Given these preconditions, we think overpaying may be particularly useful for pharmacy-based cost groups.


Subject(s)
Insurance Carriers/economics , Insurance Carriers/statistics & numerical data , Insurance, Health/statistics & numerical data , Morbidity , Risk Adjustment/organization & administration , Chronic Disease/epidemiology , Health Services/statistics & numerical data , Health Status , Humans , Models, Theoretical , Risk Adjustment/economics
6.
Eur J Health Econ ; 17(9): 1059-1072, 2016 Dec.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-26613608

ABSTRACT

In health insurance, voluntary deductibles are offered to the insured in return for a premium rebate. Previous research has shown that 11 % of the Dutch insured opted for a voluntary deductible (VD) in health insurance in 2014, while the highest VD level was financially profitable for almost 50 % of the population in retrospect. To explain this discrepancy, this paper identifies and discusses six potential determinants of the decision to opt for a VD from the behavioral economic literature: loss aversion, risk attitude, ambiguity aversion, debt aversion, omission bias, and liquidity constraints. Based on these determinants, five potential strategies are proposed to increase the number of insured opting for a VD. Presenting the VD as the default option and providing transparent information regarding the VD are the two most promising strategies. If, as a result of these strategies, more insured would opt for a VD, moral hazard would be reduced.


Subject(s)
Decision Making , Deductibles and Coinsurance/economics , Financing, Personal/economics , Insurance, Health/economics , Consumer Behavior , Health Expenditures , Health Policy/legislation & jurisprudence , Humans , Mandatory Programs , Netherlands , Private Sector , Risk
7.
Health Policy ; 119(5): 688-95, 2015 May.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-25747511

ABSTRACT

To counteract moral hazard in health insurance, insured can be offered a voluntary deductible (VD) in return for a premium rebate. In the Dutch mandatory basic health insurance however, only 11 per cent of the insured opted for a VD in 2014. Several determinants could affect the decision to opt for a VD. This paper examines one of these determinants: the financial profitability. A VD is profitable for the consumer if the out-of-pocket expenses do not exceed the offered premium rebate. The empirical analyses, based upon individual-level data on costs and characteristics of over 800,000 Dutch insured, show that a VD of €500 on top of the mandatory deductible of €360 would have been financially profitable for 48 per cent of the Dutch insured given the average premium rebate of € 240 in 2014. If the whole population had a VD, most insured would obtain either the maximum loss (44 per cent) or the maximum gain (41 per cent). A VD is profitable for males, young insured, healthy insured and insured with few healthcare expenses in the past. To further reduce moral hazard, the following strategies can be used to increase the number of insured opting for a VD: provide insured with information regarding the VD and introduce a shifted deductible.


Subject(s)
Consumer Behavior , Deductibles and Coinsurance/economics , Healthcare Financing , Insurance, Health/economics , Age Factors , Female , Health Expenditures , Humans , Male , Netherlands
8.
Med Care Res Rev ; 72(2): 220-43, 2015 Apr.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-25694164

ABSTRACT

This study provides a taxonomy of measures-of-fit that have been used for evaluating risk-equalization models since 2000 and discusses important properties of these measures, including variations in analytic method. It is important to consider the properties of measures-of-fit and variations in analytic method, because they influence the outcomes of evaluations that eventually serve as a basis for policymaking. Analysis of 81 eligible studies resulted in the identification of 71 unique measures that were divided into 3 categories based on treatment of the prediction error: measured based on squared errors, untransformed errors, and absolute errors. We conclude that no single measure-of-fit is best across situations. The choice of a measure depends on preferences about the treatment of the prediction error and the analytic method. If the objective is measuring financial incentives for risk selection, the only adequate evaluation method is to assess the predictive performance for non-random groups.


Subject(s)
Risk Adjustment , Data Interpretation, Statistical , Humans , Models, Statistical , Policy Making , Risk Adjustment/classification , Risk Adjustment/methods
9.
Eur J Health Econ ; 16(2): 201-18, 2015 Mar.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-24519402

ABSTRACT

Currently-used risk-equalization models do not adequately compensate insurers for predictable differences in individuals' health care expenses. Consequently, insurers face incentives for risk rating and risk selection, both of which jeopardize affordability of coverage, accessibility to health care, and quality of care. This study explores to what extent the predictive performance of the prediction model used in risk equalization can be improved by using additional administrative information on costs and diagnoses from three prior years. We analyze data from 13.8 million individuals in the Netherlands in the period 2006-2009. First, we show that there is potential for improving models' predictive performance at both the population and subgroup level by extending them with risk adjusters based on cost and/or diagnostic information from multiple prior years. Second, we show that even these extended models do not adequately compensate insurers. By using these extended models incentives for risk rating and risk selection can be reduced substantially but not removed completely. The extent to which risk-equalization models can be improved in practice may differ across countries, depending on the availability of data, the method chosen to calculate risk-adjusted payments, the value judgment by the regulator about risk factors for which the model should and should not compensate insurers, and the trade-off between risk selection and efficiency.


Subject(s)
Health Expenditures/statistics & numerical data , Insurance Carriers/economics , Insurance, Health/economics , Models, Statistical , Risk Adjustment/methods , Adolescent , Adult , Age Factors , Aged , Child , Child, Preschool , Cost Sharing , Female , Humans , Infant , Infant, Newborn , Male , Middle Aged , Netherlands , Policy , Risk Factors , Sex Factors , Socioeconomic Factors , Young Adult
10.
J Health Econ ; 28(1): 198-209, 2009 Jan.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-18996607

ABSTRACT

In health insurance, a traditional deductible (i.e. with a deductible range [0,d]) is in theory not effective in reducing moral hazard for individuals who know (ex-ante) that their expenditures will exceed the deductible amount d, e.g. those with a chronic disease. To increase the effectiveness, this paper proposes to shift the deductible range to [s(i),s(i)+d], with starting point s(i) depending on relevant risk characteristics of individual i. In an empirical illustration we assume the optimal shift to be such that the variance in out-of-pocket expenditures is maximized. Results indicate that for the 10-percent highest risks in our data the optimal starting point of a euro1000-deductible is to be found (far) beyond euro1200, which corresponds with a deductible range of [1200,2200] or further. We conclude that, compared to traditional deductibles, shifted deductibles with a risk-adjusted starting point lower out-of-pocket expenditures and may further reduce moral hazard.


Subject(s)
Deductibles and Coinsurance/ethics , Insurance, Health/economics , Risk Adjustment/economics , Adolescent , Adult , Aged , Female , Health Expenditures , Health Status , Humans , Male , Middle Aged , Models, Econometric , Young Adult
11.
J Health Econ ; 27(2): 427-43, 2008 Mar.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-18178276

ABSTRACT

The presence of voluntary deductibles in the Swiss and Dutch mandatory health insurance has important implications for the respective risk equalization systems. In a theoretical analysis, we discuss the consequences of equalizing three types of expenditures: the net claims that are reimbursed by the insurer, the out-of-pocket expenditures and the expenditure savings due to moral hazard reduction. Equalizing only the net claims, as done in Switzerland, creates incentives for cream skimming and prevents insurers from incorporating out-of-pocket expenditures and moral hazard reductions into their premium structure. In an empirical analysis, we examine the effect of self-selection and conclude that the Swiss and Dutch risk equalization systems do not fully adjust for differences in health status between those who choose a deductible and those who do not. We discuss how this may lead to incentives for cream skimming and to a reduction of cross-subsidies from healthy to unhealthy individuals compared to a situation without voluntary deductibles.


Subject(s)
Deductibles and Coinsurance , Risk Sharing, Financial , Databases as Topic , Financing, Personal , Health Expenditures , Humans , Insurance, Health/economics , Netherlands , State Medicine/economics , Switzerland
12.
Int J Health Care Finance Econ ; 7(1): 43-58, 2007 Mar.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-17431767

ABSTRACT

Theoretically, a risk avers consumer takes a deductible if the premium rebate (far) exceeds his/her expected out-of-pocket expenditures. In the absence of risk equalization, insurers are able to offer high rebates because those who select into a deductible plan have below-average expenses. This paper shows that, for high deductibles, such rebates cannot be offered if risk equalization would "perfectly" adjust for the effect of self selection. Since the main goal of user charges is to reduce moral hazard, some effect of self selection on the premium rebate can be justified to increase the viability of voluntary deductibles.


Subject(s)
Deductibles and Coinsurance/economics , Insurance, Health/economics , Choice Behavior , Cost Savings , Deductibles and Coinsurance/trends , Health Expenditures/statistics & numerical data , Humans , Insurance, Health/trends , Models, Econometric , Risk , Switzerland , Voluntary Programs
13.
Health Aff (Millwood) ; 20(3): 253-62, 2001.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-11585175

ABSTRACT

In many countries, competing health plans receive capitation payments from a sponsor, whether government or a private employer. All capitation payment methods are far from perfect and have raised concerns about risk selection. Paying health plans partly on the basis of capitation and partly on the basis of actual costs ("risk sharing") reduces plans' incentives for selection but sacrifices some incentives for efficiency. This paper summarizes our empirical research on Dutch health plans with respect to various forms of risk sharing. All sponsors can improve their payment systems by either implementing or changing their form of risk sharing.


Subject(s)
Capitation Fee , Insurance, Health/statistics & numerical data , Risk Sharing, Financial/organization & administration , Economic Competition , Efficiency, Organizational , Health Services Research , Humans , National Health Programs , Netherlands , Reimbursement, Incentive
14.
J Health Econ ; 20(2): 147-68, 2001 Mar.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-11252368

ABSTRACT

This paper describes forms of risk sharing between insurers and the regulator in a competitive individual health insurance market with imperfectly risk-adjusted capitation payments. Risk sharing implies a reduction of an insurer's incentives for selection as well as for efficiency. In a theoretical analysis, we show how the optimal extent of risk sharing may depend on the weights the regulator assigns to these effects. Some countries employ outlier or proportional risk sharing as a supplement to demographic capitation payments. Our empirical results strongly suggest that other forms of risk sharing yield better tradeoffs between selection and efficiency.


Subject(s)
Capitation Fee , Efficiency, Organizational , Insurance Selection Bias , Managed Competition/economics , Risk Sharing, Financial/methods , Cost Control/statistics & numerical data , Demography , Humans , Managed Competition/organization & administration , Models, Econometric , Netherlands , Risk Adjustment , Risk Sharing, Financial/economics
15.
J Health Econ ; 19(3): 311-39, 2000 May.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10977194

ABSTRACT

A competitive market for individual health insurance tends to risk-adjusted premiums. Premium rate restrictions are often considered a tool to increase access to coverage for high-risk individuals in such a market. However, such regulation induces selection which may have several adverse effects. As an alternative approach we consider risk-adjusted premium subsidies. Empirical results of simulated premium models and subsidy formulae are presented. It is shown that sufficiently adjusted subsidies eliminate the need for premium rate restrictions and consequently avoid their adverse effects. Therefore, the subsidy approach is the preferred strategy to increase access to coverage for high-risk individuals.


Subject(s)
Economic Competition , Fees and Charges , Financing, Government , Insurance Coverage/economics , Insurance, Health/economics , Risk Adjustment , Fees and Charges/statistics & numerical data
16.
Health Policy ; 53(2): 123-41, 2000 Sep.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10958993

ABSTRACT

The actuarially fair premium reduction in case of a deductible relative to full insurance is affected by: (1) out-of-pocket payments, (2) moral hazard, (3) administrative costs, and, in case of a voluntary deductible, (4) adverse selection. Both the partial effects and the total effect of these factors are analyzed. Moral hazard and adverse selection appear to have a substantial effect on the expected health care costs above a deductible but a small effect on the expected out-of-pocket expenditure. A premium model indicates that for a broad range of deductible amounts the actuarially fair premium reduction exceeds the deductible.


Subject(s)
Cost Sharing/statistics & numerical data , Deductibles and Coinsurance/statistics & numerical data , Fees and Charges/statistics & numerical data , Insurance, Health/economics , Actuarial Analysis , Fees and Charges/standards , Health Expenditures/statistics & numerical data , Health Services , Humans , Insurance Selection Bias , Insurance, Health/statistics & numerical data , Motivation , Netherlands , Rate Setting and Review/methods , Rate Setting and Review/standards
17.
Health Care Manag Sci ; 3(2): 131-40, 2000 Feb.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10780281

ABSTRACT

Under inadequate capitation formulae competing health insurers have an incentive for cream skimming, i.e., the selection of enrollees whom the insurer expects to be profitable. When evaluating different capitation formulae, previous studies used various indicators of incentives for cream skimming. These conventional indicators are based on all actual profits and losses or on all predictable profits and losses. For the latter type of indicators, this paper proposes, as a new approach, to ignore the small predictable profits and losses. We assume that this new approach provides a better indication of the size of the cream skimming problem than the conventional one, because an insurer has to take into account its costs of cream skimming and the (statistical) uncertainties about the net benefits of cream skimming. Both approaches are applied in theoretical and empirical analyses. The results show that, if our assumption is right, the problem of cream skimming is overestimated by the conventional ways of measuring incentives for cream skimming, especially in the case of relatively good capitation formulae.


Subject(s)
Capitation Fee/organization & administration , Economic Competition/organization & administration , Insurance Selection Bias , Managed Care Programs/organization & administration , Models, Econometric , Motivation , Adult , Female , Forecasting , Humans , Male , Marketing of Health Services , Reproducibility of Results
18.
Soc Sci Med ; 47(2): 223-32, 1998 Jul.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-9720641

ABSTRACT

Risk-adjusted capitation payments (RACPs) to competing health insurers are an essential element of market-oriented health care reforms in many countries. RACPs based on demographic variables only are insufficient, because they leave ample room for cream skimming. However, the implementation of improved RACPs does not appear to be straightforward. A solution might be to supplement imperfect RACPs with a form of mandatory pooling that reduces the incentives for cream skimming. In a previous paper it was concluded that high-risk pooling (HRP), is a promising supplement to RACPs. The purpose of this paper is to compare HRP with two other main variants of mandatory pooling. These variants are called excess-of-loss (EOL) and proportional pooling (PP). Each variant includes ex post compensations to insurers for some members which depend to various degrees on actually incurred costs. Therefore, these pooling variants reduce the incentives for cream skimming which are inherent in imperfect RACPs, but they also reduce the incentives for efficiency and cost containment. As a rough measure of the latter incentives we use the percentage of total costs for which an insurer is at risk. This paper analyzes which of the three main pooling variants yields the greatest reduction of incentives for cream skimming given such a percentage. The results show that HRP is the most effective of the three pooling variants.


Subject(s)
Capitation Fee/organization & administration , Health Care Sector/organization & administration , Insurance Pools/legislation & jurisprudence , National Health Programs/organization & administration , Risk Sharing, Financial , Cost Control , Economic Competition/organization & administration , Efficiency, Organizational , Forecasting , Health Care Reform , Health Services Research , Humans , Insurance Selection Bias , Netherlands , Regression Analysis
19.
Health Policy ; 39(2): 123-35, 1997 Feb.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10165042

ABSTRACT

In many countries regulated competition among health insurance companies has recently been proposed or implemented. A crucial issue is whether or not the benefits package offered by competing insurers should also cover catastrophic risks (like several forms of expensive long-term care) in addition to non-catastrophic risks (like hospital care and physician services). In 1988 the Dutch government proposed compulsory national health insurance based on regulated competition among insurer as well as among providers of care. The competing insurers should offer a benefits package covering both non-catastrophic risks and catastrophic risks. The insurers would be largely financed via risk-adjusted capitation payments. The government intended to use a capitation formula that is, besides some demographic variables, based on multi-year prior costs. This paper presents the results of an explorative empirical analysis of the possible consequences of such a capitation formula for catastrophic risks. The main conclusion is that this formula would be inadequate because it would leave ample room for cream skimming.


Subject(s)
Capitation Fee , Catastrophic Illness/economics , National Health Programs/economics , Single-Payer System/economics , Costs and Cost Analysis , Economic Competition , Fraud , Health Care Reform , Humans , Insurance Selection Bias , Netherlands , Risk Management
20.
Soc Sci Med ; 43(5): 655-66, 1996 Sep.
Article in English | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-8870130

ABSTRACT

In many (predominantly) publicly financed health care systems market-oriented health care reforms are being implemented or have been proposed. The purpose of these reforms is to make resource allocation in health care more efficient, more innovative and more responsive to consumers preferences while maintaining equity. At the same time, the advances in technology result in a divergence of consumers' preferences with respect to health care and urge society to (re)think about the meaning of the solidarity principle in health care. In this paper we indicate some international trends in health care reforms and explore some potential future options. From an international perspective we can observe a trend towards universal mandatory health insurance, contracts between third-party purchasers and the providers of care, competition among providers of care and a strengthening of primary care. These trends can be expected to continue. A more controversial issue is whether there should also be competition among the third-party purchasers and whether in the long run there will occur a convergence towards some "ideal" model. Although regulated competition in health care can be expected to yield more value for money, it might yield both more efficiency and higher total costs. It has been argued that equity can be maintained in a competitive health care system if we interpret equity as "equal access to cost-effective care within a reasonable period of time". Because the effectiveness of care has to be considered in relation to the medical indication and the condition of the patient, the responsibility for cost-effective care rests primarily with the providers of care. Guidelines and protocols should be developed by the profession and sustained by financial incentives embedded in contracts. It has been argued that the third-party purchasers could start to concentrate on the contracts with the primary care physicians. Contracts with other providers could then be a natural complement to these contracts. Coordinated-care contracts between the third-party purchasers and the consumer of care could provide the consumer with monetary incentives to go to efficient providers. A consumer choice of insurance contract could give the consumer an opportunity to make important choices in health care. However, each society has to make its own choices about what care should be available to everybody independent of an individual's purchasing power.


Subject(s)
Economic Competition , Global Health , Health Care Reform/economics , Insurance, Health , Models, Organizational , Community Participation , Health Care Reform/trends , Humans , Insurance, Health/economics , Insurance, Health/trends
SELECTION OF CITATIONS
SEARCH DETAIL
...