Your browser doesn't support javascript.
loading
Mostrar: 20 | 50 | 100
Resultados 1 - 20 de 31
Filtrar
1.
Neurology ; 58(1): 37-43, 2002 Jan 08.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-11781403

RESUMO

OBJECTIVE: To determine the prevalence, expenditures, and utilization of enrollees with MS relative to all enrollees in privately insured, Medicare, and Medicaid populations. METHODS: The authors used insurer administrative billing data to identify persons with MS, their insured medical expenditures and utilization, and benchmark general insured population expenditures and utilization. Three samples of insurer billing data were analyzed: nationally representative samples for the privately insured (1994 through 1995) and Medicare (1996 though 1997) populations, and Medicaid data for disabled (1991 through 1996) populations from six states. RESULTS: Using 2 years of diagnoses on claims, the prevalence of MS in the privately insured population was 24 per 10,000, 36 per 10,000 in the Medicare population, and 71 per 10,000 in the Medicaid disabled population. Annual insured expenditures were $7,677 per privately insured enrollee with MS vs $2,394 for all privately insured enrollees, $13,048 per Medicare beneficiary with MS compared with $6,006 for all Medicare beneficiaries, and $7,352 per Medicaid disabled recipient with MS vs $4,088 per disabled recipient without MS. Home health expenditures were very high for Medicare beneficiaries with MS and nursing facility expenditures were very high for Medicaid disabled recipients with MS. A small proportion of enrollees with MS accounted for most expenditures. CONCLUSIONS: Insured enrollees with MS are two to three times more expensive than average insured enrollees. If the premiums that employers or governments pay health insurers and the capitation amounts that insurers pay health care providers do not account for these higher costs, a disincentive is created for the enrollment and care of persons with MS.


Assuntos
Gastos em Saúde , Seguro Saúde , Esclerose Múltipla/economia , Adolescente , Adulto , Idoso , Feminino , Custos de Cuidados de Saúde , Humanos , Masculino , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada , Medicaid , Medicare , Pessoa de Meia-Idade , Prevalência , Estados Unidos
2.
Med Care ; 39(11): 1188-202, 2001 Nov.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-11606873

RESUMO

BACKGROUND: Risk adjustment models typically use diagnoses from claims or encounter records to assess illness severity. However, concerns about the availability and reliability of diagnostic data raise the potential for alternative methods of risk adjustment. Here, we explore the use of pharmacy data as an alternative or complement to diagnostic data in risk adjustment. OBJECTIVES: To develop and test a pharmacy-based risk adjustment model for SSI and TANF Medicaid populations. RESEARCH DESIGN: Pharmacological review combined with empirical evaluation. We developed the Medicaid Rx model, a system that classifies a subset of the National Drug Codes into categories that can be used for risk-assessment and risk-adjusted payment. SUBJECTS: Subjects consisted of 362,370 persons with disability and 1.5 million AFDC and TANF beneficiaries in California, Colorado, Georgia, and Tennessee during 1990-1999. MEASURES: We compare pharmacy and diagnostic classification for three chronic diseases. We also compare R2 statistics and use simulated health plans to evaluate the performance of alternative models. RESULTS: Pharmacy and diagnostic classification vary in their ability to identify specific chronic disease. Using simulated plans, diagnostic models are better at predicting expenditures than are pharmacy-based models for disabled Medicaid beneficiaries, although the models perform similarly for TANF Medicaid beneficiaries. Models that combine diagnostic and pharmacy data have superior overall performance. CONCLUSIONS: The performance of risk adjustment models using a combination of pharmacy and diagnostic data are superior to that of models using either data source alone, particularly among TANF beneficiaries. Concerns regarding variations in prescribing patterns and the incentives that may follow from linking payment to pharmacy use warrant further research.


Assuntos
Doença Crônica/classificação , Serviços de Diagnóstico/classificação , Medicaid/estatística & dados numéricos , Modelos Econométricos , Assistência Farmacêutica/classificação , Risco Ajustado/métodos , Índice de Gravidade de Doença , Adulto , Fatores Etários , California , Criança , Doença Crônica/tratamento farmacológico , Doença Crônica/economia , Colorado , Bases de Dados Factuais , Serviços de Diagnóstico/estatística & dados numéricos , Pessoas com Deficiência/estatística & dados numéricos , Georgia , Gastos em Saúde , Humanos , Medicaid/economia , Assistência Farmacêutica/estatística & dados numéricos , Estudos Prospectivos , Análise de Regressão , Tennessee , Estados Unidos
4.
J Health Polit Policy Law ; 26(5): 993-1001, 2001 Oct.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-11765276

RESUMO

Arrow asserted that a variety of institutional arrangements and observable mores of the medical profession were functional responses to the failure of the market to insure against uncertainties. But one of these norms--the ethic to provide treatment without regard to ability to pay--was also a response to the failure of the political system to assure the elderly and poor would not suffer more than others when they got sick. This ethic is strikingly different from the norm in most other areas of the economy. Automobile dealers and department stores are not expected to give away their products to the poor; neither are grocery stores or farmers. Public education is a closer analogy, reflecting the norm that all children deserve a good education. In education, however, unlike in medicine, we collectively support this norm by providing public funds to accomplish this goal rather than by relying on the private market. In 1963, physicians argued that a combination of the market and private philanthropy (including the obligations of physicians) would be sufficient to guarantee high-quality care for the elderly and the poor. Government financing, they argued, would lead to socialized medicine, impairing relationships between physicians and patients and between physicians and society. Based on his article, Arrow would not have agreed. Neither, apparently, did the public. The enactment of Medicare indicated, in part, that many people understood, even in 1965, the extent to which treatment choices and outcomes were affected by ability to pay. Events since 1965 suggest that there is some tension between insurance and ethical responses to uncertainty despite Arrow's endorsement of both. I have argued here that Medicare and Medicaid further eroded the ethic that treatment should be available without regard to ability to pay by reducing physician willingness to provide charity care and by reducing the resources available to public hospitals and the interest of private teaching hospitals in providing care to the uninsured poor. Largely independent of Medicare and Medicaid, the increasing importance of pharmaceuticals and other services delivered outside of the hospital further strengthened the connection between treatment choices and ability to pay, and the growth of capitated payment systems made this connection salient to many insured patients and their physicians. In part, then, the AMA was correct: Medicare and Medicaid have contributed to the erosion of trust in physicians as incorruptible agents for patients. Some of this trust undoubtedly was misplaced, even in 1965, and trust alone was not sufficient to guarantee widespread access to medical care or to assure that treatment provided would take true social benefits and costs into account. Medicare and Medicaid, as well as the growth of prepayment insurance plans, represent institutional responses to the failure of the 1963 norms to accomplish societal goals. Still, as we have seen, these responses create their own challenges, and we continue to search for institutions that will allow widespread insurance to coexist with the physician-patient trust that Arrow correctly identified as an important response to uncertainties and information asymmetries in the medical care market.


Assuntos
Instituições de Caridade/economia , Economia Médica/tendências , Setor de Assistência à Saúde/tendências , Modelos Econômicos , Seguridade Social/economia , Cuidados de Saúde não Remunerados/economia , Instituições de Caridade/tendências , Competição Econômica , Economia Médica/história , Setor de Assistência à Saúde/história , Necessidades e Demandas de Serviços de Saúde/economia , História do Século XX , Seguro Saúde/tendências , Responsabilidade Social , Valores Sociais , Seguridade Social/história , Cuidados de Saúde não Remunerados/tendências , Estados Unidos
5.
Health Care Financ Rev ; 21(3): 29-64, 2000.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-11481767

RESUMO

This article describes the Chronic Illness and Disability Payment System (CDPS), a diagnostic classification system that Medicaid programs can use to make health-based capitated payments for TANF and disabled Medicaid beneficiaries. The authors describe the diversity of diagnoses and different burdens of illness among disabled and AFDC Medicaid beneficiaries. Claims from seven States are analyzed, and payment weights are provided that States can use when adjusting HMO payments. The authors also compare the taxonomy and statistical performance of CDPS to other leading diagnostic classification systems and find that the new model performs better in a number of respects.


Assuntos
Doença Crônica/economia , Grupos Diagnósticos Relacionados/economia , Gastos em Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Reembolso de Seguro de Saúde , Medicaid/economia , Modelos Econométricos , Adulto , Ajuda a Famílias com Filhos Dependentes/economia , Capitação , Criança , Doença Crônica/classificação , Doença Crônica/epidemiologia , Efeitos Psicossociais da Doença , Humanos , Revisão da Utilização de Seguros , Estados Unidos/epidemiologia
6.
Health Aff (Millwood) ; 18(2): 30-47, 1999.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10091430

RESUMO

The decline in health insurance coverage among workers from 1979 to 1995 can be accounted for almost entirely by the fact that per capita health care spending rose much more rapidly than personal income during this time period. We simulate health insurance coverage levels for 1996-2005 under alternative assumptions concerning the rate of growth of spending. We conclude that reduction in spending growth creates measurable increases in health insurance coverage for low-income workers and that the rapid increase in health care spending over the past fifteen years has created a large pool of low-income workers for whom health insurance is unaffordable.


Assuntos
Cobertura do Seguro/estatística & dados numéricos , Seguro Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Pessoas sem Cobertura de Seguro de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Adulto , Planos de Assistência de Saúde para Empregados/economia , Planos de Assistência de Saúde para Empregados/estatística & dados numéricos , Planos de Assistência de Saúde para Empregados/tendências , Gastos em Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Gastos em Saúde/tendências , Política de Saúde , Humanos , Renda/estatística & dados numéricos , Renda/tendências , Cobertura do Seguro/economia , Cobertura do Seguro/tendências , Seguro Saúde/economia , Seguro Saúde/tendências , Modelos Logísticos , Pessoa de Meia-Idade , Estados Unidos
7.
J Health Polit Policy Law ; 24(5): 1099-106, 1999 Oct.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10615621

RESUMO

Managed care has done a better job at reducing expenditure growth than it has in improving quality. Although reduced expenditure growth is not appreciated by many, it has real benefits. For the majority of Americans who are privately insured, it results in greater disposable income for goods and services other than health care (although the illusion of employer-paid health insurance obscures this reality for many). For Medicaid programs, slower growth of expenditures facilitates efforts at expanding coverage. For low-income workers, slower expenditure growth results in larger numbers of people retaining insurance coverage than would have been the case if premiums rose more quickly. While there are some victories to which managed care organizations can point, we cannot credibly argue that overall levels of quality and health outcomes are improving as the health care system is massively disrupted by changes in health care finance and delivery. The disruptions create real hardships for some physicians and other health care workers, and worries for many consumers. These worries fuel the managed care backlash. The danger is that politicians will respond to these worries with policies that inhibit the development of high-quality delivery systems. The opportunity is for relatively modest public policy changes--external review organizations, better public-sector purchasing capabilities, public investment in producing and publicizing information on health plan and medical group performance, and establishment of a public ombudsperson--to respond to consumer worries and lead to improvements in health care quality and outcomes. Finally, I would be remiss without a reminder that the single most effective action politicians could take to improve health care quality and outcomes would be to change the rules of health care financing to assure that all Americans are covered by managed care. Even with all of its inadequacies, managed care is much superior to the patchwork care available to the 43 million Americans who are uninsured. The managed care backlash is concerned with protecting patients who are insured (and their providers). Far more valuable would be to protect those without insurance. Sadly, no politician has yet figured out how to do this. Still waiting.


Assuntos
Atitude Frente a Saúde , Política de Saúde , Acessibilidade aos Serviços de Saúde , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada , Humanos , Cobertura do Seguro , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/organização & administração , Medicaid/organização & administração , Pessoas sem Cobertura de Seguro de Saúde , Medicare/organização & administração , Política , Estados Unidos
9.
Manag Care Q ; 4(2): 26-37, 1996.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10172616

RESUMO

The Community Medical Alliance in Boston has adapted principles of prepaid managed care to redesign service delivery for people with severe physical disability and with late-stage AIDS. Experience to date suggests that the flexibility of capitation can be used to substantially shift care from its usual hospital focus to clinicians in home and community settings, especially nurse practitioners, with a high degree of patient satisfaction and without apparent compromise in quality. Instead of limiting access, managed care can use prepayment to support early interventions, coordination, and the development of services specifically designed to meet the needs of the target population.


Assuntos
Síndrome da Imunodeficiência Adquirida/terapia , Planejamento em Saúde Comunitária/organização & administração , Prestação Integrada de Cuidados de Saúde/organização & administração , Pessoas com Deficiência , Boston , Capitação , Prestação Integrada de Cuidados de Saúde/economia , Prestação Integrada de Cuidados de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Custos de Cuidados de Saúde , Política de Saúde , Humanos , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/economia , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/organização & administração , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/estatística & dados numéricos , Profissionais de Enfermagem , Satisfação do Paciente , Avaliação de Programas e Projetos de Saúde , Gestão da Qualidade Total , Revisão da Utilização de Recursos de Saúde
10.
Health Care Financ Rev ; 17(3): 7-33, 1996.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-10172665

RESUMO

This article describes a system of diagnostic categories that Medicaid programs can use for adjusting capitation payments to health plans that enroll people with disability. Medicaid claims from Colorado, Michigan, Missouri, New York, and Ohio are analyzed to demonstrate that the greater predictability of costs among people with disabilities makes risk adjustment more feasible than for a general population and more critical to creating health systems for people with disability. The application of our diagnostic categories to State claims data is described, including estimated effects on subsequent-year costs of various diagnoses. The challenges of implementing adjustment by diagnosis are explored.


Assuntos
Capitação , Pessoas com Deficiência/classificação , Medicaid/economia , Métodos de Controle de Pagamentos/métodos , Adolescente , Adulto , Idoso , Avaliação da Deficiência , Pessoas com Deficiência/estatística & dados numéricos , Feminino , Custos de Cuidados de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Humanos , Masculino , Medicaid/organização & administração , Medicaid/estatística & dados numéricos , Pessoa de Meia-Idade , Modelos Econômicos , Análise de Regressão , Gestão de Riscos , Estados Unidos
12.
Inquiry ; 32(1): 41-55, 1995.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-7713617

RESUMO

This article explores how to reward health plans that serve people with disabilities and residents of low-income areas. We analyze health care expenditure patterns for Medicaid-covered persons with disabilities in Ohio, Missouri, Minnesota, and Wisconsin, demonstrating that diagnostic classifications are predictably related to resource utilization, and that health care expenditures are much more predictable for persons with disabilities than for the nondisabled. The implications of this analysis for risk-adjusted payment systems are explored. We also consider methods of assuring that health plans will provide high-quality care to the residents of inner city neighborhoods.


Assuntos
Seleção Tendenciosa de Seguro , Seguro Saúde , Medição de Risco , Análise Atuarial , Ajuda a Famílias com Filhos Dependentes/economia , Ajuda a Famílias com Filhos Dependentes/estatística & dados numéricos , Pessoas com Deficiência/estatística & dados numéricos , Gastos em Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Acessibilidade aos Serviços de Saúde/economia , Acessibilidade aos Serviços de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Humanos , Seguro Saúde/economia , Seguro Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Medicaid/estatística & dados numéricos , Minnesota , Missouri , Pobreza/economia , Pobreza/estatística & dados numéricos , Estados Unidos , Wisconsin
18.
N Engl J Med ; 328(2): 148-52, 1993 Jan 14.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-8416437

RESUMO

BACKGROUND: The theory of managed competition holds that the quality and economy of health care delivery will improve if independent provider groups compete for consumers. In sparsely populated areas where relatively few providers are required, however, it is not feasible to divide the provider community into competing groups. We examined the demographic features of health markets in the United States to see what proportion of the population lives in areas that might successfully support managed competition. METHODS: The ratios of physicians to enrollees in large staff-model health maintenance organizations were determined as an indicator of the staffing needs of an efficient health plan. These ratios were used to estimate the populations necessary to support health organizations with various ranges of specialty services. Metropolitan areas with populations large enough to support managed competition were identified. RESULTS: We estimated that a health care services market with a population of 1.2 million could support three fully independent plans. A population of 360,000 could support three plans that independently provided most acute care hospital services, but the plans would need to share hospital facilities and contract for tertiary services. A population of 180,000 could support three plans that provided primary care and many basic specialty services but that shared inpatient cardiology and urology services. Health markets with populations greater than 180,000 would include 71 percent of the U.S. population; those with populations greater than 360,000, 63 percent; and those with populations greater than 1.2 million, 42 percent. CONCLUSIONS: Reform of the U.S. health care system through expansion of managed competition is feasible in medium-sized or large metropolitan areas. Smaller metropolitan areas and rural areas would require alternative forms of organization and regulation of health care providers in order to improve quality and economy.


Assuntos
Área Programática de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Planos Médicos Alternativos/organização & administração , Política de Saúde/economia , Necessidades e Demandas de Serviços de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/organização & administração , Adolescente , Adulto , Idoso , Planos Médicos Alternativos/economia , Planos Médicos Alternativos/estatística & dados numéricos , Competição Econômica/organização & administração , Sistemas Pré-Pagos de Saúde/economia , Acessibilidade aos Serviços de Saúde/estatística & dados numéricos , Humanos , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/normas , Programas de Assistência Gerenciada/estatística & dados numéricos , Pessoa de Meia-Idade , Densidade Demográfica , Estados Unidos
19.
Ann Intern Med ; 117(7): 599-606, 1992 Oct 01.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-1524334

RESUMO

OBJECTIVE: To examine the effects of advance directives on medical treatments and on patient satisfaction and well-being and to determine whether the enhancement of patient autonomy through advance directives provides a more ethically feasible approach to cost control than does the imposition of limits through rationing. DESIGN: Randomized, controlled trial. SETTING: University and Veterans Affairs medical center. PATIENTS: Two hundred and four patients with life-threatening illnesses, 100 of whom died after enrollment in the study. INTERVENTION: Patients randomly assigned to the experimental group were offered the California Durable Power of Attorney (a typical proxy-instruction directive), and patients assigned to the control group were not offered the advance directive. Hospital admissions were monitored to assure that a summary of the document was present in the active medical record at each hospitalization. MEASUREMENTS: Cognitive function, patient satisfaction, psychological well-being, health locus of control, sense of coherence, health-related quality of life, receipt of medical treatments, and medical treatment charges. RESULTS: No significant differences were found between advance-directive and control groups regarding psychosocial variables, health outcome variables, and medical treatments or charges. Patients offered an advance directive had an average hospital stay of 40.8 days (95% CI, 32.2 to 49.4 days), compared with an average of 33.1 days (95% CI, 26.0 to 40.2 days) for controls. Patients offered an advance directive were charged an average of $19,502 (95% CI, $13,030 to $25,974) for medical treatments in the last month of life compared with $19,700 (95% CI, $13,704 to $25,696) for controls. CONCLUSIONS: Despite claims that public demand for longer life accounts for rising medical costs, most surveys suggest that patients are calling for less, not more, of the expensive, high-technology treatment often used in terminal phases of illness. Executing the California Durable Power of Attorney for Health Care and having a summary copy placed in the patient's medical record had no significant positive or negative effect on a patient's well-being, health status, medical treatments, or medical treatment charges.


Assuntos
Diretivas Antecipadas/economia , Cuidados para Prolongar a Vida/estatística & dados numéricos , Satisfação do Paciente/estatística & dados numéricos , Medição de Risco , Diretivas Antecipadas/psicologia , California , Grupos Controle , Controle de Custos/métodos , Hospitais Universitários , Hospitais de Veteranos , Humanos , Cuidados para Prolongar a Vida/economia , Autonomia Pessoal , Estudos Prospectivos , Alocação de Recursos , Suspensão de Tratamento
20.
Inquiry ; 29(2): 213-30, 1992.
Artigo em Inglês | MEDLINE | ID: mdl-1612721

RESUMO

The primary justification for private insurance is the hypothesis that competition among private insurers will lead to an environment in which physicians and hospitals will continually strive to improve the quality and economy of the care they provide, and to be responsive to the preferences of the consumers they serve. However, to date, competition among private insurers has failed miserably in achieving this goal. In order to achieve this goal, competition among insurers must be regulated in an entirely different manner than it is currently. This article describes the ways in which health insurance is currently regulated, and argues that passive regulation directed at assuring financial solvency of insurers should be transformed into an active purchasing authority. This purchasing authority would empower the demand side, creating an environment of managed competition that rewarded those provider groups able to offer high quality, economical care.


Assuntos
Defesa do Consumidor , Competição Econômica , Seguro Saúde/economia , Marketing de Serviços de Saúde/economia , Poder Psicológico , Humanos , Seguro Saúde/normas , Marketing de Serviços de Saúde/métodos , Pensões , Sistemas Políticos , Estados Unidos
SELEÇÃO DE REFERÊNCIAS
DETALHE DA PESQUISA
...